PRESCRIPTIVE LABOUR MIGRATION, NATIONAL SAVINGS DETERMINATION AND INCOME CONSUMPTION RATIONALITY FUNCTION
Journal of Economics and Trade, Volume 7, Issue 2,
Page 53-61
DOI:
10.56557/jet/2022/v7i28116
Abstract
Profit plough back and savings for investment underpin the economic growth of businesses and individuals. When the economy is not doing well, prompted by calamities like Covid-19 or occasioned by ordinary life cycles, individuals seek to migrate seeking job opportunities that pay better, enabling them to save for investment, eventually increasing welfare. Economic entities left at home continue to look for ways of mobilizing savings for growth. This article proposes analytic solutions to the labour migration and national savings problem by determining activation rationality pay-off, the labour migration rationality threshold and computing national savings using the income consumption rationality function deriving from the entropy rationality model – a behavioural framework that determines economic rationality exercised by an economic agent on a percentage scale. It is hoped that the proposed analytic solutions will be found useful by especially labour migrants and labour policymakers in this exponentially global growing society.
- Income consumption rationality function
- activation rationality
- activation rationality savings trade-off
- labour migration remuneration threshold
- cogni-economic pressure
How to Cite
References
Pawasutipaisit A, Townsend RM. Wealth accumulation and factors accounting for success. J Econom. 2011;161(1):56-81.
Kaur B, Singh JM, Garg BR, Singh J, Singh S. Causes and impact of labour migration: A case study of Punjab agriculture. Agric Econ Res Rev. 2011;24:(347-2016-16993):459-466.
Hermele K. The discourse on migration and development. In: International migration, immobility and development. Routledge. 2021; 133-58.
Clark C. National income and outlay. Routledge; 2019.
Kirika SK. Monetary de-measurement of taxation using cogni-economic pressure coefficient on a continuous progressivity model: towards equitable taxation for Kenya. Cogent Econ Fin. 2020;8(1):1804038.
Gevorkyan AV, Mashuryan K, Gevorkyan A. Economics of labor migration from Armenia: a conceptual study. [Universitäts-und Landesbibliothek Sachsen-Anhalt]; 2006.
Chotikapanich D, Griffiths WE, Rao DSP. Estimating and combining national income distributions using limited data. J Bus Econ Stat. 2007;25(1):97-109.
Smelker MW. Problems of estimating spending and saving in long-range projections. In: Long-range economic projection. Vol. 16. Princeton University Press. 2015;333-64.
Fernandez-Corugedo E. Consumption theory. Centre for Central Banking Studies, Bank of England; 2004.
Alimi RS. Keynes’ absolute income hypothesis and Kuznets paradox; 2013.
Friedman M. The permanent income hypothesis. NBER Chapters. 1957:20-37.
World Bank Group. 2016: digital dividends. World Dev Rep; 2016.
Mankiw NG. Principles of microeconomics. Cengage Learning; 2017.
Modigliani F. Life cycle, individual thrift, and the wealth of nations. Science. 1986;234 (4777):704-12.
Buchholz K. Where people are self-employed around the world. Labor market; 2019, August 5.
Kim JK. An international labour migration to developing countries in Asia: a case study of Korea. Korea J Popul Dev. 1996;25(2):287-332.
Simon HA. Models of bounded rationality: empirically grounded economic reason. MIT Press. 1997; 3.
Smith A. The wealth of nations [1776]. Vol. 11937. na; 1937.
Business D. World Bank Group. Електронний ресурс; 2020. http://www.doingbusiness.org/ExploreTopics/PayingTaxes/CompareAll.aspx
Kirika SK. Determinants of financial decision-making rationality in deposit-taking cooperatives in Kenya (Doctoral dissertation, Jomo Kenyatta University of Agriculture and Technology); 2017.
-
Abstract View: 0 times
PDF Download: 0 times